Extended Harmony, and Tiger Repellent Drumming
Attention conservation notice: Almost 1000 words of
follow-up to a post on an inter-blog dispute, complete with graphs and leaden
sarcasm.
Some follow-up to the last post, in response to
e-mails, and discussion elsewhere.
- Non-capitalist societies can and do, of course, also have lots of
inequality. So?
- I do not see why my aside about capitalism and state power should be the
least bit controversial. Since my libertarian friends seem more comfortable
with deduction from first principles than empirical observation, let's try it
this way. Capitalism needs private property. Since there will be disputes
about property, there must be an institution for settling those disputes
effectively. That institution is the state. (Yes, I know about
anarcho-capitalist ideas for private, market-driven courts and policing. These
would last about a week: at best, they would re-sort themselves into
territorial states, or more likely those doing the guard labor would ask
themselves what they guard should belong to someone else.) Capitalism thus
presumes a state which decides who owns what, and is (almost) unquestioningly
obeyed. Again: capitalism needs contracts, there will be disputes about
contracts, there must be an institution which can settle those disputes. Thus
capitalism presumes a state which can decide who owes what to whom, and force
them to pay. Capitalism with intellectual property is even more demanding:
copyright presumes a state exercising minute control over the content of all
modes of communication; patents presume a state exercising minute control over
processes of production and the use of knowledge. (And then we can get into
what the state has to do by way
of culture and education,
i.e., reshaping the mentality of the
population.) When such powers are used stupidly or capriciously, capitalism
suffers, but when such powers are absent, capitalism does not exist.
Now, continuing with the theme of harmonizing means and ends, if you want
capitalism, but you find a state that powerful very scary (as you have every
right to do), then you have a problem. You might, on reflection, favor some
other economic system which does not require such a powerful state. (This is
not a popular option, save among marginal advocates of rural poverty and
idiocy.) You might, on reflection, decide that such power is perfectly A-OK,
so long as it's used for ends you approve of and there's no danger of the
people taking over. (Hence Hayek's anti-democratic political ideas, and
viewing Pinochet's
reign of terror as less damaging to [what he saw as] liberal values than
the British National Health Service.) Or you might try to find ways of taming
or domesticating state power, of civilizing it. (I think that has a pretty
good track-record, but who knows how long we can keep it up?) What you cannot
do, with any intellectual honesty or even hope of getting what you want, is
pretend that capitalism can work without a powerful, competent and intrusive
state. As Ernest Gellner
once wrote,
"Political control of economic life is not the consummation of world history,
the fulfilment of destiny, or the imposition of righteousness; it is a painful
necessity."
- I should have made clearer that the policies which have been sold over the
last few decade as enhancing economic growth have little show for themselves on
that score. A crude but still illuminating way to see this is simply to plot
GDP per person over time, adjusted for inflation:
|
Data from the
St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank's FRED service: GDP from
the GDPCA
series, population from
the POP
series. The plot starts at 1952 because that's when the population series
does. |
I've plotted this with a log scale on the vertical axis, so the slope indicates
the (exponential) rate of growth. The slope does not change very much over
time, though it seems to become less steep as time goes on. This visual impression is confirmed if we look at growth rates:
|
Annual
exponential growth rates from the previous figure: yearly values (dots) and an 11-year moving average (black line). (The correlation time of the growth rate series is about 3.5 years.) |
What these graphs bring to mind is the ancient joke where a new doctor is
examining a patient in an insane asylum. The lunatic is compulsively banging
on a drum, and the doctor asks why. "To repel the tigers, of course." Doctor:
"Tigers? There are no tigers for thousands of miles!" Lunatic: "You see how
well it works." If you want to say that the more deregulatory,
capitalism-unleashed direction in which policy has moved since the 1980s (or
even the late 1970s) is growth-enhancing, you can't point to an acceleration of
growth, since there hasn't been any
(pace
Eugene Fama
and John
Taylor). Instead, you have to argue, counter-factually, that without those
policy changes, growth would have slowed down (even more than it did); that
pounding those drums drove away the tigers of stagnation. It's
not completely illogical to try to explain a more-or-less constant
growth rate with a variable policy regime, but you need some story about what
other variables policy is compensating for, and indeed a story about why the
compensation is so close.
At a finer-grained level, you can look
at performance
over the business cycle, and again see that the new policy regime doesn't
deliver any more aggregate growth. It certainly doesn't lead
to faster
productivity growth
(again, despite
claims to the contrary). But one thing which has changed is
that aggregate
growth does a lot less for most people than it used to. Again, you could
tell a counter-factual stories about how all of these would be much worse
without those policies, but by this point you are claiming that your drumming
repels not just tigers but
also snow
leopards, elephants,
and Glyptodon.
Manual trackback: Agnostic Liberal;
Doubting Marcus
The Dismal Science;
The Progressive Forces
Posted at August 01, 2011 09:50 | permanent link