←April→
Sun |
Mon |
Tue |
Wed |
Thu |
Fri |
Sat |
|
|
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
11 |
12 |
13 |
14 |
15 |
16 |
17 |
18 |
19 |
20 |
21 |
22 |
23 |
24 |
25 |
26 |
27 |
28 |
29 |
30 |
|
|
|
Archives
Categories
Self-Centered
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur
Books (etc.) I've read this month and
feel I can recommend (warning: I have no taste)
- Palani Mohan, Hunting with Eagles: In the Realm of the Mongolian Kazakhs
- Beautiful black-and-white photographs of, as it says, Mongolian Kazakhs hunting with eagles, and their landscape. Many of them are just stunningly composed.
Upcoming Talks
Upcoming Talks
- Statistics Department, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 13--17 and 20--22 March 2017
- A short course on "Nonparametric tools for statistical network modeling",
based on 36-781.
- Santa Fe Institute, Complex Systems Summer School, 20--21 June 2017
- Exact dates tentative.
|
April 01, 2025
The Books I Am Not Going to Write
Attention conservation notice: Middle-aged dad contemplating "aut liberi, aut libri" on April 1st.
... and why I am not going to write them.
- Re-Design for a Brain
- W. Ross Ashby's Design for a Brain: The Origins of Adaptive
Behavior is a deservedly-classic and influential book. It also contains
a lot of sloppy mathematics, in some cases in important places. (For instance,
there are several crucial points where he implicitly assumes that deterministic
dynamical systems cannot be reversible or volume-preserving.) This project
would simply be re-writing the book so as to give correct proofs, with
assumptions clearly spelled out, and seeing how strong those assumptions need
to be, and so how much more limited the final conclusions end up being.
- Why I am not going to write it: It would be of interest to
about five other people.
- The Genealogy of Complexity
- Why I am not going to write it: It no longer seems as
important to me as it did in 2003.
- The Formation of the Statistical Machine Learning Paradigm, 1985--2000
- Why I am not going to write it: It'd involve a lot of work
I don't know how to do --- content analysis of CS conference
proceedings and interviews with the crucial figures while they're
still around. I feel like I could
fake my way through get up
to speed on content analysis, but oral history?!?
- Almost None of the Theory of Stochastic Processes
- Why I am not going to write it: I haven't taught the class since 2007.
- Statistical Analysis of Complex Systems
- Why I am not going to write it: I haven't taught the class since 2008.
- A Child's Garden of Statistical Learning Theory
- Why I am not going to write it: Reading Ben Recht has made me doubt whether the stuff I understand and teach is actually worth anything at all.
- The Statistics of Inequality and Discrimination
- I'll just quote the course description:
Many social questions about inequality, injustice and unfairness are, in part, questions about evidence, data, and statistics. This class lays out the statistical methods which let us answer questions like "Does this employer discriminate against members of that group?", "Is this standardized test biased against that group?", "Is this decision-making algorithm biased, and what does that even mean?" and "Did this policy which was supposed to reduce this inequality actually help?" We will also look at inequality within groups, and at different ideas about how to explain inequalities between and within groups.
The idea is to write a book which could be used for a course on inequality,
especially in the American context where we're obsessed by between-group
inequalities, for quantitatively-oriented students and
teachers, without either pandering, or pretending that being STEM-os
lets us clear everything up easily. (I have heard too many engineers and
computer scientists badly re-inventing basic sociology and economics in this
context...)
- Why I am not going to write it: Nobody wants to hear that
these are real social issues; that understanding these issues requires numeracy
and not just moralizing; that social scientists have painfully acquired
important knowledge about these issues (though not enough); that social
phenomena are emergent so they do not just reflect the motives of the people
involved (in particular: bad things happen just because the people you already
loathe are so evil; bad things don't stop happening just because nobody wants
them); or that no amount of knowledge about how society is and could be will
tell us how it should be. So writing the book I want will basically get me
grief from every direction, if anyone pays any attention at all.
- Huns and Bolsheviks
- To quote an old notebook: "the Leninists were like the Chinggisids and the Timurids, and similar Eurasian powers: explosive rise to dominance over a wide area of conquest, remarkable horrors, widespread emulation of them abroad, elaborate patronage of sciences and arts, profound cultural transformations and importations, collapse and fragmentation leaving many successor states struggling to sustain the same style. But Stalin wasn't Timur; he was worse. (Likewise, Gorbachev was better than Ulugh Beg.)"
- Why I am not going to write it: To do it even half-right, relying entirely on secondary sources, I'd have to learn at least four languages. Done well or ill, I'd worry about someone taking it seriously.
- The Heuristic Essentials of Asymptotic Statistics
- What my students get sick of hearing me refer to as "the usual
asymptotics". A first-and-last course in statistical theory, for people who
need some understanding of it, but are not going to pursue it professionally,
done with the same level of mathematical rigor (or, rather, floppiness) as a
good physics textbook. --- Ideally of course it would also be useful for those
who are going to pursue theoretical statistics professionally, perhaps
through a set of appendices, or after-notes to each chapter, highlighting the
lies-told-to-children in the main text. (How to give those parts the acronym
"HFN", I don't know.)
- Why I am not going to write it: We don't teach a course
like that, and it'd need to be tried out on real students.
- Actually, "Dr. Internet" Is the Name of the Monsters' Creator
- Why I am not going to write it: Henry will finally have
had enough of my nonsense as a supposed collaborator and write it on his own.
- Logic Is a Pretty Flower That Smells Bad
- Seven-ish pairs of chapters. The first chapter in each pair highlights a
compelling idea that is supported by a logically sound deduction from
plausible-sounding premises. The second half of the pair then lays out the
empirical evidence that the logic doesn't describe the actual world at all.
Thus the book would pair Malthus on population with the demographic revolution
and Boserup, Hardin's tragedy of the commons with Ostrom, the Schelling model
with the facts of American segregation, etc. (That last is somewhat unfair to
Schelling, who clearly said his model wasn't an explanation of how we
got into this mess, but not at all unfair to many subsequent economists. Also,
I think it'd be an important part of the exercise that at least one of the
"logics" be one I find compelling.) A final chapter would reflect on
the role of good arguments in keeping bad ideas alive, the importance of scope
conditions, Boudon's "hyperbolic" account of ideology, etc.
- Why I am not going to write it: I probably should write it.
- Beyond the Orbit of Saturn
- Historical cosmic horror mind candy: in 1018, Sultan Mahmud of Ghazni
receives reports that the wall which (as the Sultan understands things)
Alexander built high in the Hindu Kush to contain Gog and Magog is decaying.
Naturally, he summons his patronized and captive scholars to figure out what to
do about this. Naturally, the rivalry between al-Biruni and ibn Sina flares
up. But there is something up there, trying to get out, something
not even the best human minds of the age can really comprehend...
- Why I am not going to write it: I am very shameless about
writing badly, but I find my attempts at fiction more painful than
embarrassing.
Self-Centered;
Modest Proposals
Posted at April 01, 2025 00:30 | permanent link
March 31, 2025
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, March 2025
Attention
conservation notice: I have no taste, and no qualification to opine on
pure mathematics, sociology, or adaptations of Old English epic poetry. Also,
most of my reading this month was done at odd hours and/or while chasing after
a toddler, so I'm less reliable and more cranky than usual.
- Philippe Flajolet and Robert Sedgewick, Analytic Combinatorics
[doi:10.1017/CBO9780511801655]
- I should begin by admitting that I have never learned much
combinatorics, and never really liked what I did learn. To say my
knowledge topped out at Stirling's approximation to $n!$ is only
a mild exaggeration. Nonetheless, after reading this book, I think I begin to
get it. I'll risk making a fool of myself by explaining.
- We start with some class $\mathcal{A}$ of discrete, combinatorial objects, like a type of
tree or graph obeying some constraints and rules of construction. There's a
notion of "size" for these objects (say, the number of nodes in the graph, or
the number of leaves in the tree). We are interested in counting the number
of objects of size $n$. This gives us a sequence $A_0, A_1, A_2, \ldots A_n, \ldots$.
- Now whenever we have a sequence of numbers $A_n$, we can encode it in a "generating function"
\[
A(z) = \sum_{n=0}^{\infty}{A_n z^n}
\]
and recover the sequence by taking derivatives at the origin:
\[
A_n = \frac{1}{n!} \left. \frac{d^n A}{dz^n} \right|_{z=0}
\]
(I'll claim the non-mathematician's privilege of not worrying about whether the series converges, the derivatives exist, etc.) When I first encountered this idea as a student, it seemed rather pointless to me --- we define the generating function in terms of the sequence, so why do we need to differentiate the GF to get the sequence?!? The trick, of course, is to find indirect
ways of getting the generating function.
- Part A of the book is about what the authors call the "symbolic method" for
building up the generating functions of combinatorial classes, by expressing
them in terms of certain basic operations on simpler classes. The core
operations, for structures with unlabeled parts, are disjoint union, Cartesian
product, taking sequences, taking cycles, taking multisets, and taking power
sets. Each of these corresponds to a definite transformation of the generating
function: if $\mathcal{A}$s are ordered pairs of $\mathcal{B}$s and $\mathcal{C}$s (so the operation is Cartesian product), then $A(z) = B(z)
C(z)$, while if $\mathcal{A}$s are sequences of $\mathcal{B}$s, then $A(z) = 1/(1-B(z))$, etc.
(Chapter I.) For structures with labeled parts, slightly different, but
parallel, rules apply. (Chapter II.) These rules can be related very
elegantly to constructions with finite automata and regular languages, and to
context-free languages. If one is interested not just in the number of objects
of some size $n$, but the number of size $n$ with some other "parameter" taking
a fixed value (e.g., the number of graphs on $n$ nodes with $k$ nodes of degree
1), multivariate generating functions allow us to count them, too (Chapter
III). (Letting $k$ vary for fixed $n$ of course gives a probability
distribution.) When the parameters of a complex combinatorial object are
"inherited" from the parameters of the simpler objects out of which it is
built, the rules for transforming generating functions also apply.
- In favorable cases, we get nice expressions (e.g., ratios of polynomials)
for generating functions. In less favorable cases, we might end up with
functions which are only implicitly determined, say as the solution to some
equation. Either way, if we now want to decode the generating function $A(z)$
to get actual numbers $A_1, A_2, \ldots A_n, \ldots$, we have to
somehow extract the coefficients of the power series. This is the subject of
Part B, and where the "analytical" part of the title comes in. We turn to
considering the function $A(z)$ as a function on the complex plane.
Specifically, it's a function which is analytic in some part of the
plane, with a limited number of singularities. Those singularities turn out to
be crucial: "the location of a function's singularities dictates the
exponential growth of its coefficients; the nature of a functions singularities
determine the subexponential factor" (p. 227, omitting symbols). Accordingly,
part II is a crash course in complex analysis for combinatorists, the upshot of
which is to relate the coefficients in power series to certain integrals around
the origin. One can then begin to approximate those integrals, especially for
large $n$. Chapter V carries this out for rational and "meromorphic"
functions, ch. VI for some less well-behaved ones, with applications in
ch. VII. Chapter VIII covers a somewhat different way of approximating the
relevant integrals, namely the saddle-point method, a.k.a. Laplace
approximation applied to contour integrals in the complex plane.
- Part C, consisting of Chapter IX, goes back to multivariate generating
functions. I said that counting the number of objects with size $n$ and parameter $k$ gives us, at each fixed $n$, a probability distribution over $k$. This chapter considers the convergence of these probability distributions as $n \rightarrow \infty$, perhaps after suitable massaging / normalization. (It accordingly includes a crash course in convergence-in-distribution for
combinatorists.) A key technique here is to write the multivariate generating function as a small perturbation of a univariate generating function, so that
the asymptotics from Part B apply.
- There are about 100 pages of appendices, to fill gaps in the reader's
mathematical background. As is usual with such things, it helps to have at
least forgotten the material.
- This is obviously only for mathematically mature readers. I have spent a
year making my way through it, as time allowed, with pencil and paper at hand.
But I found it worthwhile, even enjoyable, to carve out that time. §
- (The thing which led me to this, initially, was trying to come up with an
answer to "what on Earth
is the cumulative generating function doing?" If we're dealing with
labeled structures, then the appropriate generating function is what the
authors call the "exponential generating function", $A(z) =
\sum_{n=0}^{\infty}{A_n z^n / n!}$. If $A$'s are built as sets of $B$'s, then
$A(z) = \exp(B(z))$. Turned around, then, $B(z) = \log{A(z)}$ when $A$'s are
composed as sets of $B$'s. So if the moments of a random variable
could be treated as counting objects of a certain size, so $A_n = \mathbb{E}\left[ X^n \right]$
is somehow the number of objects of size $n$, and we can interpret these objects as
sets, the cumulant generating function would be counting the number of
set-constituents of various sizes. I do not regard this as a very satisfying
answer, so I am going to have to learn even more math.)
- Arthur L. Stinchcombe, Information and Organizations [Open access]
- A series of essays on organizations --- mostly for-profit corporations, but
also universities --- as information-processing systems. The main thesis is
that organizations "[grow] toward sources of news, news about the uncertainties
that most affect their outcomes" (pp. 5--6), and then react to that news on an
appropriate (generally, quick) time-scale. This is a functionalist idea, but
Stinchcombe is careful to try to make it work, making arguments about how an
organization's need to perform these functions comes to be felt by
actual people in the organization, people who are in positions to do something
about it. (Usually, his arguments on this score are persuasive.) This is by
far the best thing I've seen in sociology about social structures as
information-processing systems; I'm a bit disappointed in myself that I didn't
read it a long time ago. §
- Zach Weinersmith and Boulet, Bea Wolf
- The first part of Beowulf, through the defeat of Grendel,
adapted into a comic-book about joyously ill-behaved kids in an American
suburb. Rather incredibly, it works.
- (Thanks to Jan Johnson for the book.)
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur;
Mathematics;
Automata and Calculating Machines;
Enigmas of Chance;
Commit a Social Science;
The Dismal Science;
The Collective Use and Evolution of Concepts;
The Commonwealth of Letters
Posted at March 31, 2025 23:59 | permanent link
January 22, 2025
The Distortion Is Inherent in the Signal
Attention conservation notice: An overly-long blog comment, at the unhappy intersection of political theory and hand-wavy social network theory.
Henry Farrell
has a
recent post on how "We're getting the social media crisis wrong". I think
it's pretty much on target --- it'd be surprising
if I didn't! --- so I want to encourage my readers to become its readers.
(Assuming I still have any readers.) But I also want to improve on it. What
follows could have just been a comment on Henry's post, but I'll post
it here because I feel like pretending it's 2010.
Let me begin by massively compressing Henry's argument. (Again, you should
read him, he's clear and persuasive, but just in case...) The real bad thing
about actually-existing social media is not that it circulates falsehoods and
lies. Rather it's that it "creates publics with malformed collective
understandings". Public opinion doesn't just float around like a glowing cloud
(ALL
HAIL) rising nimbus-like from the populace. Rather, "we rely on a variety
of representative technologies to make the public visible, in more or less
imperfect ways". Those technologies shape public opinion. One way in
particular they can shape public opinion is by creating and/or maintaining
"reflective beliefs", lying somewhere on the spectrum between cant/shibboleths
and things-you're-sure-someone-understands-even-if-you-don't. (As
an heir of the French
Enlightenment, many of Dan Sperber's original examples of such "reflective
beliefs" concerned Catholic dogmas like trans-substantiation; I will more
neutrally say that I have a reflective belief that botanists can distinguish
between alders and poplars, but don't ask me which tree is which.)
Now, at this point, Henry references
a 2019 article
in Logic magazine rejoicing in the title "My Stepdad's Huge Data
Set", and specifically the way it distinguishes between those who
merely consume Internet porn, and the customers who actually
fork over money, who "convert". To quote the article: "Porn companies, when
trying to figure out what people want, focus on the customers who convert. It's
their tastes that set the tone for professionally produced content and the
industry as a whole." To quote Henry: "The result is that particular taboos
... feature heavily in the presentation of Internet porn, not because they are
the most popular among consumers, but because they are more likely to convert
into paying customers. This, in turn, gives porn consumers, including
teenagers, a highly distorted understanding of what other people want and
expect from sex, that some of them then act on...."
To continue quoting Henry:
Something like this explains the main consequences of social media for politics. The collective perspectives that emerge from social media --- our understanding of what the public is and wants --- are similarly shaped by algorithms that select on some aspects of the public, while sidelining others. And we tend to orient ourselves towards that understanding, through a mixture of reflective beliefs, conformity with shibboleths, and revised understandings of coalitional politics.
At this point, Henry goes on to contemplate some recent grotesqueries from
Elon Musk and Mark Zuckerberg. Stipulating that those are, indeed, grotesque,
I do not think they get at the essence of the problem Henry's identified, which
I think is rather more structural than a couple of mentally-imploding
plutocrats. Let me try to lay this out sequentially.
- The distribution of output (number of posts) etc. over users is strongly
right-skewed. Even if everyone's content is equally engaging, and equally
likely to be encountered, this will lead to a small minority having a really
disproportionate impact on what people perceive in their feeds.
- Connectivity is also strongly right-skewed. This is somewhat
endogenous to algorithmic choices on the part of
social-media system operators, but not entirely.
(One algorithmic choice is to make "follows" an asymmetric relationship.
[Of course, the fact that the "pays attention to" relationship is asymmetric
has been a source of jokes and drama since time out of mind, so maybe that's
natural.] Another is to make acquiring followers cheap, or even free. If
people had to type out the username of everyone they wanted to see a post,
every time they posted, very few of us would maintain
even a hundred
followers, if that.)
- Volume of output, and connectivity, are at the very least
not negatively associated. (I'd be astonished if they're not
positively associated but I can't immediately lay hands on relevant
figures.) *
- People who write a lot are weird. As a sub-population, we are,
let us say, enriched for those who are obsessed with niche interests. (I very
much include myself in this category.) This of course continues Henry's
analogy to porn; "Proof is left as an exercise for the reader's killfile", as
we used to say on Usenet. **
- Consequence: even if the owners of the systems didn't put their thumbs on
the scales, what people see in their feeds would tend to reflect the
pre-occupations of a comparatively small number of weirdos. Henry's points
about distorted collective understandings follow.
Conclusion: Social media is a machine for "creat[ing] publics with malformed collective understandings".
The only way I can see to avoid reaching this end-point is if what we
prolific weirdos write about tends to be a matter of deep indifference to
almost everyone else. I'd contend that in a world
of hate-following,
outrage-bait and lolcows, that's not very plausible. I have not done justice
to Henry's discussion of the coalitional aspects of all this, but suffice it to
say that reflective beliefs are often reactive, we're-not-like-them
beliefs, and that people are very sensitive to cues as to which
socio-political coalition's output they are seeing. (They may not always
be accurate in those inferences,
but they definitely draw
them ***.) Hence I do not think much
of this escape route.
--- I have sometimes fantasized about a world
where social media are
banned, but people are allowed to e-mail snapshots and short letters to their
family and friends. (The world would, un-ironically, be better off if more
people were showing off pictures of their lunch, as opposed
to meme-ing
each other into contagious hysterias.) Since, however, the technology of
the mailing list with automated sign-on dates back to the 1980s, and the
argument above says that it alone would be enough to create distorted
publics, I fear this is another case
where Actually,
"Dr. Internet" Is the Name of the Monsters' Creator.
(Beyond all this, we know that the people who use social media are not
representative of the population-at-large.
[ObCitationOfKithAndKin: Malik, Bias
and Beyond in Digital Trace Data.] For that matter, at least in the
early stages of their spread, online social networks spread through
pre-existing social communities, inducing further distortions.
[ObCitationOfNeglectedOughtToBeClassicPaper: Schoenebeck, "Potential Networks,
Contagious Communities, and Understanding Social Network Structure",
arxiv:1304.1845.] As I write,
you can see this happening with BlueSky. But I think the argument
above would apply even if we signed up everyone to one social media site.)
*: Define "impressions" as the product of "number of posts per unit time" and "number of followers". If those both have power-law tails, with exponents \( \alpha \) and \( \beta \) respectively, and are independent, then impressions will have a power-law tail with exponent \( \alpha \wedge \beta \), i.e., slowest decay rate wins. )To see this, set \( Z = XY \) so \( \log{Z} = \log{X} + \log{Y} \), and the pdf of \( \log{Z} \) is, by independence, the convolution of the pdfs of \( \log{X} \) and \( \log{Y} \). But those both have exponential tails, and the slower-decaying exponential gives the tail decay rate for the convolution.) The argument is very similar if both are log-normal, etc., etc. --- This does not account for amplification by repetition, algorithmic recommendations, etc. ^
**: Someone sufficiently
flame-proof could make a genuinely valuable study of this point by scraping the
public various fora for written erotica and doing automated content
analysis. I'd bet good money that the right tail of prolificness is dominated
by authors with very niche interests. [Or, at least, interests which
were niche at the time they started writing.] But I could not, in good
conscience, advise anyone reliant on grants to actually do this study, since
it'd be too cancellable from too many directions at
once. ^
***: As a small example I
recently overheard in a grocery store, "her hair didn't used to be such a
Republican blonde" is a perfectly comprehensible
statement. ^
Actually, "Dr. Internet" Is the Name of the Monsters' Creator;
Kith and Kin
Posted at January 22, 2025 15:12 | permanent link
November 25, 2024
Tenure-Track Opening in Computational Social Science at CMU (a.k.a. Call to Pittsburgh, 2024 edition)
Attention
conservation notice: Advertising an academic position in fields you
don't work in, in a place you don't want to live, paying much less than
the required skills can get from private industry.
We have a tenure-track opening at the intersection of statistics and complex
social systems, a.k.a. computational social science:
The Department of Statistics and Data Science at Carnegie Mellon University invites applications for a tenure track position in Computational Social Science at the rank of Assistant Professor starting in Fall 2025. This position will be affiliated with the Institute for Complex Social Dynamics.
The Department seeks candidates in the areas of social science statistics and data science, as well as related interdisciplinary fields. Potential areas of interest include network science, social simulation, data science for social good, simulation-based inference, cultural evolution, using large text and image corpora as data, and data privacy. Candidates with other research interests related to the work of both the Department and the Institute are also highly encouraged to apply.
The Institute for Complex Social Dynamics brings together scholars at Carnegie Mellon University who develop and apply mathematical and computational models to study large-scale complex social phenomena. The core members of the Institute are based in the Departments of Statistics and Data Science, Social and Decision Sciences, and Philosophy. Interests of the Institute include studies of the emergence of social behavior, the spread of misinformation, social inequality, and societal resilience.
As tenure-track faculty, the successful candidate will be expected to develop an independent research agenda, leading to publications in leading journals in both statistics and in suitable social-scientific venues; to teach courses in the department at both the undergraduate and graduate level; to supervise Ph.D. dissertations; to obtain grants; and in general to build a national reputation for their scholarship. The candidate will join the ICSD as a Core Member, and help shape the future of the Institute.
CMU's statistics department is unusually welcoming to those without
traditional disciplinary backgrounds in statistics (after all, I'm here!), and
that goes double for this position. If this sounds interesting,
then apply by December 15th.
(I'm late in posting this.) If this sounds like it would be interesting to
your doctoral students / post-docs / other proteges,
then encourage them to apply.
(If you'd like to join the statistics department, but are not interested in
complex social dynamics what's wrong with you? we
have another tenure
track opening, where I'm not on the hiring committee.)
Kith and Kin;
Enigmas of Chance
Posted at November 25, 2024 10:30 | permanent link
November 14, 2024
Come Post-Doc with Me!
Attention
conservation notice: Soliciting applications for a limited-time
research job in an arcane field you neither understand nor care about, which
will at once require specialized skills and pay much less than those skills
command in industry.
I am, for the first time, hiring a post-doc:
The Department of Statistics and Data Science at Carnegie Mellon University invites applicants for a two-year post-doctoral fellowship in simulation-based inference. The fellow will work with Prof. Cosma Shalizi of the department on developing theory, algorithms and applications of random feature methods in simulation-based inference, with a particular emphasis on social-scientific problems connected to the work of CMU's Institute for Complex Social Dynamics. Apart from by the supervisor, the fellow will also be mentored by other faculty in the department and the ICSD, depending on their interests and secondary projects, and will get individualized training in both technical and non-technical professional skills.
Successful applicants will have completed a Ph.D. in Statistics, or a related quantitative discipline, by September 2025, and ideally have a strong background in non-convex and stochastic optimization and/or Monte Carlo methods, and good programming and communication skills. Prior familiarity with simulation-based inference, social network models and agent-based modeling will be helpful, but not necessary.
Basically, I need someone who is much better than I am at stochastic
optimization to help out with
the matching-random-features idea. But I hope my
post-doc will come up with other things to do, unrelated to their ostensible
project (God knows I did), and I promise not to put my name on anything unless
I actually contribute. If you don't have a conventional background in
statistics, well, I'm open to that,
for obvious reasons.
Beyond that, the stats. department is a genuinely great and supportive place
to work, I hope for fabulous things from ICSD, and CMU has a whole has both a
remarkable number of people doing interesting work and remarkably low barriers
between departments; Pittsburgh is a nice and still-affordable place to live.
Apply, by 15 December!
--- If I have sold you on being a post-doc here, but not on my project
or on me, may I interest you in working on social
networks dynamics with my esteemed colleague Nynke Niezink?
(The post-doc ad is official, but this blog post is just me, etc., etc.)
Self-Centered
Posted at November 14, 2024 23:20 | permanent link
October 17, 2024
30 Years of Notebooks
Attention
conservation notice: Middle-aged dad has doubts about how he's spent
his time.
In September 1994, I wanted to write a program which would filter the Usenet
newsgroups I followed for the posts of most interest to me, which led me to
writing out keywords describing what I was interested in. I don't remember why
I started to elaborate the keywords into little essays and reading lists
(perhaps self-clarification?), but I did, and then, because I'd just learned
HTML and was playing around with hypertext, I put the document online. (My
records say this was 3 October 1994, though that may have been fixing on a
plausible date retroactively.) I've
been updating those notebooks ever
since, recording things-to-read as they crossed my path, recording my
reading, and some thoughts. The biggest change in organization came pretty
early: the few people who read it all urged me to split it from one giant file
into many topical files, so I did, on 13 March 1995, ordered by last update, a
format I've stuck to ever since (*).
This was not, of course, what I was supposed to be doing as a
twenty-year-old physics graduate student. (Most of the notebook entries
weren't even about physics.) Unlike a lot of ideas I had at that age, though,
I stuck with it --- have stuck with it. Over the last thirty years,
I've spent a substantial chunk of my waking hours recording references,
consolidating what I understand by trying to explain it, and working out what I
think by seeing what I write, by using Emacs to edit a directory of very basic
HTML files. (I
learned Emacs
Lisp to write functions to do things like add links
to arxiv.)
Was any of this a good use of my time? I couldn't begin to say. Long, long
ago it became clear to me that I was never going to read more than a small
fraction of the items I recorded as "To read:". I sometimes tell myself that
it's a way of satiating my hoarding tendencies without actually filling my
house with junk, but of course it's possible it's just feeding those
tendencies. I do use the notebooks, though honestly the have-read
portions are the most useful ones to me. Some of the notebooks have grown into
papers, though many more which were intended to be seeds of papers have never
sprouted. I know that some other people, from time to time, say they find them
useful, which is nice. (Though I presume most people's reactions would range
from bafflement to "wow, pretentious much?") Whether this justifies all those
hours not writing papers / finishing any of my projected books / gardening /
hanging out with friends / being with my family / playing with my cat (RIP) /
drinking beer / riding my bike / writing letters / writing al-Biruni fanfic /
actually reading, well...
The core of the matter, I suspect, is that if anyone does anything
for a decade or three consistently, it becomes a very hard habit to break. By
this point, the notebooks are so integrated into the way I work that it would
take lots of my time and will-power to
stop updating them, as long as I keep anything like my current job.
So I will keep at it, and hope that it is, at worst, a cheap and harmless vice.
I never did write that Usenet filter.
*: A decade later, I started
using blosxom, rather than completely
hand-written HTML, and Danny Yee wrote me a
cascading style sheet. I also was happy to use
first HTMX, and
then MathJax, to render math, rather than
trying to put equations into HTML. ^.
Posted at October 17, 2024 09:30 | permanent link
October 04, 2024
The Professoriate Considered as a Super-Critical Branching Process
Attention
conservation notice: Academic navel-gazing, in the form of basic
arithmetic with unpleasant consequences that I leave partially
implicit.
A professor at a top-tier research university who graduates only six
doctoral students over a thirty year career is likely regarded by their
colleagues as a bit of a slacker when it comes to advising work; it's easy to
produce many more new Ph.D.s.
(Here is a more
representative case of some personal relevance.) That slacking professor has
nonetheless reproduced their own doctorate six-fold, which works out to
$\frac{\log{6}}{30} \approx$ 6% per year growth in the number of Ph.D. holders.
Put this as a lower bound --- a very cautious lower bound --- on how quickly
the number of doctorates could grow, if all those doctorate-holders
became professors themselves. Unless faculty jobs also grow at 6% per
year, which ultimately means student enrollment growing at 6% per year,
something has to give. Student enrollment does not grow at 6% per
year indefinitely (and it cannot, even if you think everyone should go
to college); something gives. What gives is that most Ph.D.s will not be
employed in the kind of faculty position where they train doctoral students.
The jobs they find might be good, and even make essential use of skills which
we only know how to transmit through that kind of acculturation and
apprenticeship, but they simply cannot be jobs whose holders spawn more Ph.D.s.
The professoriate is a super-critical branching process, and
we know how those end. (I am a neutron that didn't get
absorbed by a moderator; that makes me luckier than those that did get
absorbed, not better.) In the sustainable steady state, the average professor
at a Ph.D.-granting institution should expect to have one student who
also goes on to be such a professor in their entire career.
Anyone who takes this as a defense of under-funding public universities, of
adjunctification, or even of our society having more non-academic use for
quantitative skills than for humanistic learning, has trouble with reading
comprehension. Also, of course this is Malthusian reasoning; what
made Malthus wrong was not anticipating that what he called "vice"
could become universal the demographic transition. Let the reader
understand.
Learned Folly
Posted at October 04, 2024 11:00 | permanent link
September 30, 2024
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, September 2024
Attention
conservation notice: I have no taste, and no qualifications to opine
on world history,
or even
on random
matrix theory. Also, most of my reading this month was done
at odd hours and/or while chasing after a toddler, so I'm less reliable and more
cranky than usual.
- Marc Potters and Jean-Philippe Bouchaud, A First Course in Random Matrix Theory: for Physicists, Engineers and Data Scientists, doi:10.1017/9781108768900
- I learned of random matrix theory in graduate school; because of
my weird path, it was from
May's Stability and
Complexity in Model Ecosystems, which I read in 1995--1996. (I
never studied nuclear physics and so didn't encounter Wigner's ideas about
random Hamiltonians.) In the ensuing nearly-thirty-years, I've been more or
less aware that it exists as a subject, providing opaquely-named results about
the distributions of eigenvectors of matrices randomly sampled from various
distributions. It has, however, become clear to me that it's relevant to
multiple projects I want to pursue, and since I don't have one student working
on all of them, I decided to buckle down and learn some math. Fortunately,
nowadays this means downloading a pile of textbooks; this is the first of my
pile which I've finished.
- The thing I feel most confident in saying about the book, given my
confessed newbie-ness, is that Potters and Bouchaud are not kidding about their
subtitle. This is very, very much physicists' math, which is to say the kind
of thing mathematicians call "heuristic" when they're feeling
magnanimous *. I am still OK with this, despite
years of using and teaching probability theory at a rather different level of
rigor/finickiness, but I can imagine heads exploding if those with the wrong
background tried to learn from this book. (To be clear, I think more larval
statisticians should learn to do physicists' math, because it is
really good heuristically.)
- To say just a little about the content, the main tool in here is the "Stieljtes transform", which for an $N\times N$ matrix $\mathbf{A}$ with eigenvalues $\lambda_1, \ldots \lambda_N$ is a complex-valued function of a complex argument $z$,
\[
g^{\mathbf{A}}_N(z) = \frac{1}{N}\sum_{i=1}^{N}{\frac{1}{z-\lambda_i}}
\]
This can actually be seen as a moment-generating function, where the $k^{\mathrm{th}}$ "moment" is the normalized trace of $\mathbf{A^k}$, i.e., $N^{-1} \mathrm{tr}{\mathbf{A}^k}$. (Somewhat unusually for a moment generating function, the dummy variable is $1/z$, not $z$, and one takes the limit of $|z| \rightarrow \infty$ instead of $\rightarrow 0$.)
- The hopes are that (i) $g_N$ will converge to a limiting function as
$N\rightarrow\infty$, \[ g(z) = \int{\frac{\rho(d\lambda)}{z-\lambda}} \] and
(ii) the limiting distribution $\rho$ of eigenvalues can be extracted from
$g(z)$. The second hope is actually less problematic
mathematically **. Hope (i), the existence of a
limiting function, is just assumed here. At a very high level,
Potters and Bouchaud's mode of approach is to derive an expression for $g_N(z)$
in terms of $g_{N-1}(z)$, and then invoke the assumption (i), to get a single
self-consistent equation for the limiting $g(z)$. There are typically multiple
solutions to these equations, but also usually only one that makes sense, so
the others are ignored ***.
- At this very high level, Potters and Bouchaud derive limiting distributions
of eigenvalues, and in some cases eigenvectors, for a lot of distributions of
matrices with random entries: symmetric matrices with IID Gaussian entries,
Hermitian matrices with complex Gaussian entries, sample covariance matrices,
etc. They also develop results for deterministic matrices perturbed by random
noise, and a whole alternate set of derivations based on the replica
trick from spin glass theory, which I do not feel up to explaining. These
are then carefully applied to topics in estimating sample covariance matrices,
especially in the high-dimensional limit where the number of variables grows
with the number of observations. This in turn feeds in to a final chapter on designing optimal portfolios when covariances have to be estimated by mortals, rather than being revealed by the Oracle.
- My main dis-satisfaction with the book is that I left it without any real
feeling for why the eigenvalue density of symmetric Gaussian matrices
with standard deviation $\sigma$ approaches $\rho(x) = \frac{\sqrt{4\sigma^2 -
x^2}}{2\pi \sigma^2}$, but other ensembles have different limiting
distributions. (E.g., why is the limiting distribution only supported
on $[-2\sigma, 2\sigma]$, rather than having, say, unbounded support with
sub-exponential tails?) That is, for all the physicists' tricks used to get
solution, I feel a certain lack of "physical insight" into the forms of the
solutions. Whether any further study will make me happier on this score, I couldn't say. In the meanwhile, I'm glad I read this, and I feel more prepared to tackle the more mathematically rigorous books in my stack, and even to make some headway on my projects. §
- *: As an early example, a key step
in deriving a key result (pp. 21--23) is to get the asymptotic expected value
of such-and-such a random variable. Using
a clever trick for
computing the elements of an inverse matrix in terms of sub-matrices, they
get a formula for the expected value of the reciprocal of that variable. They
then say (eq. 2.33 on p. 22) that this is clearly the reciprocal of the desired
limiting expected value, because after all fluctuations must be
vanishing. ^
- **: We consider $z$ approaching the real axis from below, say $z=x-i\eta$ for small $\eta$. Some algebraic manipulation then makes the imaginary part of $g(x-i\eta)$ look like the convolution of the eigenvalue density $\rho$ with a Cauchy kernel of bandwidth $\eta$. A deconvolution argument then gives $\lim_{\eta \downarrow 0}{\mathrm{Im}(gx-i\eta)} = \pi \rho(x)$. This can be approximated with a finite value of $N$ and $\eta$ (p. 26 discusses the numerical error). ^
- ***: There is an interesting question about physicists' math here, actually. Sometimes we pick and choose among options that, as sheer mathematics, seem equally good, we "discard unphysical solutions". But sometimes we insist that counter-intuitive or even bizarre possibilities which are licensed by the math have to be taken seriously, physically (not quite "shut up and calculate" in its original intention, but close). I suspect that knowing when to do one rather than the other is part of the art of being a good theoretical physicist... ^
- Fernand Braudel, The Perspective of the World, volume 3 of Civilization and Capitalism, 15th--18th Century
- This is the concluding volume of Braudel's trilogy, where he tries (as the
English title indicates) to give a picture of how the world-as-a-whole worked
during this period. It's definitely the volume I find least satisfying.
Braudel organizes everything around a notion of "world economies" borrowed from
Immanuel Wallerstein
(an unfortunate choice of
guide), postulating that these are always centered on a single dominating
city, and spends a lot of his time tracking the shifts of what he says is the
dominating city of the European world economy. But by his own definition of
world economy, I don't see how there was more than one during his period,
because all his other "world economies (East Asia, India, sub-Saharan Africa,
the Americas, etc., etc.) were all tied in to the same economic system as
western-and-central Europe. In fact, Braudel goes on at great length about
these ties! (At most, Australia and Oceania might have been outside the world
economy during this period.) This is also the volume where the, let us say,
eccentricity of Braudel's economic thought began to press on me
*. It was his discussions of
cycles, "the conjuncture" and time-series decomposition which however truly
irritated me. Or, rather, it made me want to sit him down and give him a
lecture on the Yule-Slutsky effect, because I am quite
certain he was smart enough to grasp it **. --- All these remarks are, of course, the height of
presumption on my part. §
- Previously.
- *: After quoting a detailed passage from Ricardo about how both Portugal and England are better off if the former grows wine and the latter grows wheat and they exchange, Braudel spends many pages going over how Portuguese wine-growers came to rely on credit from English merchants. Stipulating that this is all true, and even stipulating that in some sense those English merchants dominated the Portuguese vintners, it does not refute Ricardo! (The cooperative socialist commonwealth will care very much about comparative advantage.) Or, again, Braudel repeatedly talks about how certain cities or countries were dis-advantaged by their high wages, without ever considering that some employers there must have felt those wages were worth paying. Indeed many employers there must have, or those would not have been the prevailing wages. --- In general, I sympathize with wanting to rescue older perspectives, here those of the mercantilists, from the condescension of posterity, but I think Braudel takes that too far, to the detriment of his understanding of his material. ^
- **: To be fair, there are some hints in those passages that Braudel might have been happy to accept Slutsky's perspective on the effect. Namely: the appearance of low-frequency cycles is the natural consequence of high-frequency noise (what Braudel would call "events") whose effects just take time to work their way through the economic system. (This reminds me that I need to actually read Barnett's biography of Slutsky one of these years.) ^
- Tamim Ansary, The Invention of Yesterday: A 50,000-Year History of Human Culture, Conflict, and Connection
- It's not quite true to say that this is an attempt to write Marshall Hodgson's never-completed world history as a volume of pop history. This is not quite true because it is also, and equally,
inspired by McNeill and McNeill's The Human Web. The result is extremely engaging, and while I didn't particularly learn from it, I daresay most of the prospective audience will not, in fact, have read as widely
in Ansary's sources as I happen to have done. §
- Errata: When describing Mesopotamian civilizations, Ansary repeatedly refers to Sumerian as a Semitic language, which is wrong. This is not particularly consequential, and I didn't notice any other errors of fact.
- Disclaimer: My grandfather and Ansary's father were friends, so
he's a family connection.
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur;
Writing for Antiquity;
The Great Transformation;
Mathematics;
Enigmas of Chance;
The Dismal Science
Posted at September 30, 2024 23:59 | permanent link
August 31, 2024
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, August 2024
Attention conservation notice: I have no taste, and no qualifications to
opine on world history. Also, most of my reading this month was done at odd hours and/or while chasing after a toddler, so I'm less reliable and more cranky than usual.
- Fernand Braudel, The Wheels of Commerce, volume 2 of Civilization and Capitalism, 15th--18th Century
- On re-reading,
I am much more struck by Braudel's constant, but un-supported, assertions about
who controlled various trades. "Power" and "control" are
unavoidably causal
notions, which means that at the very least they involve counterfactuals, the
sort of thing B. would normally say he avoids. A bit more concretely: say
Braudel is right that in the late 1500s and earlier 1600s, the European
international currency market was funneled through a small number of mostly
Genovese merchants/bankers operating at periodic fairs.
(Subsequent
scholarship seems to agree.) I'm sure those traders made money. In fact,
I'm sure that
they exploited
network externalities to make supra-normal profits. But asserting that
they controlled those currency markets implies that they could have
imposed different outcomes --- on exchange rates? on discount rates? Braudel
never bothers to say --- if they had wanted to, as opposed to having their
actions more or less dictated by the real economic activity which generated
bills of exchange, demand for currency exchange, etc. Braudel does not provide
evidence for control, and it doesn't even arise as a problem within
his horizon.
- Wishing Braudel had collaborated with someone like (impossibly) Paul
Krugman, or (more plausibly, but still impossibly) Charles Kindleberger, is both
idle and impertinent, even philistine, but I can't help it.
- Sequel.
- Glen Cook, The Black Company, Shadows Linger, The White Rose (also an omnibus, Chronicles of the Black Company, not seen by me)
- Mind candy military fantasy, in which Our Protagonists find themselves
working as mercenaries for the Dark Lord's only-barely-less-evil ex-wife, on
whom the narrator develops an unhealthy crush. (These are not spoilers.)
There are a lot of these, and I might pick up more later, but
this first trilogy comes to a satisfying ending point.
- (I'd be very surprised if these weren't an influence
on Graydon Saunders, though the prose style is rather
different.)
- Megan E. O'Keefe, The Blighted Stars
- Mind candy: a very angsty romance wrapped in a shell of space
opera. Both aspects of the story are left in media res, and I look
forward to reading the sequels.
- Phillip Kennedy Johnson et al., The Last God
- Mind candy, comic book fantasy heavily influenced by D & D.
- Wen Spencer, Tinker
- Mind candy fantasy, in which Pittsburgh is transported to Elfland for most
of each month. I read it for the local interest (admission to CMU plays a
small part of the plot, and bad things happen in Turtle Creek [which I can only
too easily believe]), and it was OK, but not good enough to make me pick up any
of the many sequels.
- Lilith Saintcrow, Moon's Knight
- Mind candy portal fantasy, in which Our Protagonist's struggles to escape
back to Mundania are rather complicated by her growing recognition that her
life there sucked, actually, and maybe fighting strange beasts and stranger
people isn't so bad in comparison...
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur;
Scientifiction and Fantastica;
Writing for Antiquity;
The Dismal Science;
Heard About Pittsburgh PA
Posted at August 31, 2024 23:59 | permanent link
July 31, 2024
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, July 2024
Attention conservation notice: I have no taste. Also, most of my reading and viewing this month was done at odd hours and/or while chasing after a toddler, so I'm less reliable and more cranky than usual.
- Elizabeth Bear, Ancestral Night
- J. S. Dewes, The Last Watch and The Exiled Fleet
- Space opera mind candy. The Bear is good, as usual, but not quite her best.
Dewes is new to me, and I'd say not quite as good at either world-building or character development as Bear, but still enjoyable, and I'll get the third book in this trilogy when it comes out.
- (Parenthetical with implicit spoilers for Ancestral Night: I
can't decide if Bear's characters are merely fooling themselves when they
assert that the Synarchy has progressed beyond money, or if Bear has not
thought through what "providing more value than you use up" is going to entail,
especially when one needs to balance, say, a recovered spacecraft hull against
expended fuel. Since Bear's narrator is, demonstrably confused about a lot of
important matters, I am inclined to think this is the character's
mis-apprehension, perhaps encouraged by propaganda. [But
then, I would.])
- Prometheus
- Spoilers for this movie from 2012 follow.
- I enjoy a good re-telling of At the Mountains of
Madness more than the next fan, and am pleased to learn that
xenomorphs are, in fact, shoggothim. (That is:
originally amorphous bits of protoplasm, built as weapons or tools, which
learned to imitate their creators and then destroyed them.) But there's a huge
part of the plot which makes no sense: if you thought humanity was the creation
of beings who were merely an advanced alien species, merely
engineers, why of why would you think they have any more of an answer to the
riddles of existence than we do, or even a way of making human bodies last
forever? The fact that the existentially-befuddled human beings in this
scenario have created intelligent androids would seem to make this obvious.
(In fact the android character basically says as much!)
- Also: Am I right in thinking that this is the first time "being infected by
the alien parasite is like being pregnant" has moved from subtext to text?
- 2001: A Space Odyssey
- Re-watched for the nth time as a palette-cleanser
after Prometheus. Icy perfection from start to finish. (The
iciness is part of the perfection.) --- The influence of Stapledon's Last and First Men and Star-Maker on Clarke, and so on this movie, is, naturally, very patent to me on this re-watch.
- The Hidden Fortress, Yojimbo, Sanjuro
- And since I was staying up late watching beloved classics... I can't
remember exactly how old I was when my father took my brother and me to see a revival of The Hidden Fortress at the old Biograph Theater in Georgetown, but we couldn't have been more than eleven, and we both imprinted. I am happy to say these movies, too, only improve with age and re-watching. §
Books to Read While Algae Grow in Your Fur;
Scientifiction and Fantastica;
Tales of Our Ancestors
Posted at July 31, 2024 23:59 | permanent link
March 23, 2024
The "Quality Control" Interview for Big Classes
Attention conservation notice: Advice on teaching, which I no longer follow myself.
I teach a lot of big classes --- the undergraduate advanced data
analysis class passed 100 students many years ago, and this spring is over
230 --- which has some predictable consequences. I don't get to talk much to
many of the students. They're mostly evaluated by how they do on weekly
problem sets (a few of which, in some classes, I call "take-home exams"), and I
don't even grade most of their homework, my teaching assistants do. While I
try to craft problem sets which make sure the students practice the skills and
material I want them to learn, and lead them to understand the ideas I want
them to grasp, just looking at their scores doesn't give me a lot of
information about how well the homework is actually working for those purposes.
Even looking at a sample of what they turn in doesn't get me very far.
If I talk to students, though, I can get a much better
sense of what they do and do not understand fairly quickly. But there really
isn't time to talk to 100 students, or 200.
About ten years ago, now, I decided to apply some of the tools of my
discipline to get out of this dilemma, by means of random sampling. Every
week, I would randomly select a fixed number of students for interviews. These
interviews took no more than 30 minutes each, usually more like 20, and were
one-on-one meetings, distinct from regular open office hours. They always
opened by me asking them to explain what they did in such-and-such a problem on
last week's homework, and went on from there, either through the problem set,
or on to other topics as those suggested themselves.
In every class I did this in, it gave me a much better sense of
what was working in the problems I was assigning and what wasn't, which topics
were actually getting through to students and which were going over their
heads, or where they learned to repeat examples mechanically without grasping
the principle. There were some things which made the interviews themselves
work better:
- Reading each students' homework, before the meeting. (Obvious in retrospect!)
- Handing the student a copy of what they turned in the week before.
(Though, as the years went on, many brought their laptops and preferred to bring
up their copy of the document there.)
- Putting a firm promise in the syllabus that nothing students said in the interview would hurt their grade. (Too many students were very nervous about it otherwise.)
- Putting an equally firm promise in the syllabus that not coming in to the interview, or blowing it off / being uncooperative, would get them a zero on that homework. (Obvious in retrospect.)
- Offering snacks at the beginning of the interview.
Setting aside a fixed block of time for these interviews didn't actually
help me, because students' schedules are too all-over-the-place for that to be
useful. (This may differ at other schools.)
Choosing the number of students each week to interview has an obvious
trade-off of instructor time vs. information. I used to adjust it so that each
student could expect to be picked once per semester, but I always did
sampling-with-replacement. In a 15-week semester with 100 students, that comes
out to about 3.5 hours of interviews every week, which, back then, I thought
well worthwhile.
I gave this up during the pandemic, because trying to do a good interview
like this over Zoom is beyond my abilities. I haven't resumed it since we went
back to in-person teaching, because I don't have the flexibility in my
schedule in any more to make it work. But I think my teaching is worse for not
doing this.
Corrupting the Young
Posted at March 23, 2024 15:10 | permanent link
The Presentation Exchange for Workshops and Classes
Attention conservation notice: Advice for running an academic workshop, which I've only followed myself a few times.
Some years ago, Henry Farrell and I
ran a series of workshops about cooperative problem-solving
and collective
cognition where we wanted to get people with very different disciplinary
backgrounds --- political theorists, computer scientists, physicists,
statisticians, cognitive psychologists --- talking to each other productively.
We hit upon an idea which worked much better than we had any right to hope.
(Whether it's ultimately due to him, or me, or to one of us tossing it out as
obviously dumb and the other saying "Actually...", neither of us can now
recall.) We've both used it separately a few times in other settings, also
with good results. Since we both found ourselves explaining it recently, I
thought I'd describe it in a brief note.
- Every participant in the workshop writes a brief presentation, with enough lead time for the organizers to read them all.
In the context of an inter-disciplinary workshop, what often works best is to describe an outstanding problem in the field.
- The workshop organizers semi-randomly assign each participant's presentation to someone else, with enough lead time that the assignee can study the presentation.
Again, in the interdisciplinary context, the organizers try to make sure that there's some hope of comprehension.
(While I called this the "presentation exchange", it needn't be a strict swap, where A gets assignd B's presentation and vice versa.)
- Everyone gives the presentation they were assigned, followed by their own comments on what they found interesting / cool / provocative and what they found incomprehensible. No one gives the presentation they wrote.
In some contexts, I have found it helpful to institute the rule that the author don't get to speak until after the presentation is finished...
Doing this at the beginning of the workshop helps make sure that everyone
has some comprehension of what everyone else is talking about, or at least that
mis-apprehensions or failures to communicate are laid bare. It can help break
up the inevitable disciplinary/personal cliques. It can, and has, spark actual
collaborations across disciplines. And, finally, many people report that
knowing their presentation is going to be given by someone else forces them to
write with unusual clarity and awareness of their own expert blind-spots.
As I said, Henry and I hit on this for interdisciplinary workshops, but I've
also used it for disciplinary workshops --- because every discipline is a
fractal (or lattice) of sub-sub-...-sub-disciplinary specialization. I've also used it for
student project classes, at both the undergrad and graduate level. That
requires more hand-holding and/or pastoral care on the part of the teacher than
a research workshop, and I've never tried to make it the way I start a
class.
Learned Folly;
The Collective Use and Evolution of Concepts;
Corrupting the Young
Posted at March 23, 2024 15:05 | permanent link
July 31, 2023
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, July 2023
Attention
conservation notice: I have no taste, and no qualifications to opine
on the sociology and industrial organization of intellectuals, political
philosophy, or American history. Also, most of my reading this month was done
at odd hours and/or while bottle-feeding a baby, so I'm less reliable and more
cranky than usual.
- Allison Brennan,
The Lost Girls,
Make Them Pay,
Breaking Point,
Too Far Gone
- Mind candy series mystery. As with many long-running series, the
soap-operatic elements keep piling up, and I honestly enjoyed those less than
seeing Lucy tackle the murder-or-kidnapping-of-the-week, but still fun. (Previously.) §
- Daniel Drezner, The Ideas Industry: How Pessimists, Partisans, and Plutocrats are Transforming the Marketplace of Ideas
- Popular social science. Drezner's main argument is as follows. He begins
by distinguishing between "public intellectuals", who are critical and
multi-sided, and "thought leaders", who have One Big Idea (if not One Weird
Trick), which they push relentlessly. (I don't think the phrase
"policy entrepreneur" appears in the book; the old-fashioned but apt
term "projector"
definitely doesn't.) Recent changes in the societies of the rich democracies
have increased the sway of thought leaders, and reduced that of public
intellectuals.
- One of these is rising economic inequality ("plutocrats"): rich people are
constitutionally more inclined to pay for advocacy, especially flattering or
self-serving advocacy, than for critique. Here Drezner advances, without much
fuss, some sensible-sounding notions about the relations between material
interests and ideology. (I actually wish he'd elaborate a theory of ideology
on this basis, but that would call for a different sort of book.)
- A second change is the rise of partisanship. This makes it easier to
ignore criticisms coming from the other side. (You will, after all, often
be right in thinking that those criticisms are made ignorantly, in bad
faith, or merely to posture before the critic's own side.) This is, of course,
bad for reason and democracy.
- The third change is the decline in trust in established institutions
("pessimism"). These have not been replaced by alternative gate-keeping
institutions, but rather by more of a free-for-all scrum for attention.
(Again: "Actually,
'Dr. Internet' is the name of the monsters' creator.") This exacerbates
already-existing tendencies in intellectual life
to highly-skewed,
winner-take-a-hell-of-a-lot outcomes. His descriptions of the temptations to
chase those rewards is vivid.
- Drezner does little to address why plutocrats, partisans, and the
plain people of the Internet should have such an appetite for intellectual
fare. It's probably impossible for social animals of our sort to conduct our
common lives without justifications and rationalizations
(cf. Mercier and Sperber). That those rationales should
be intellectual, that they should take
the form of culturally-transmitted abstractions, general ideas, appeals to impersonal principle,
appeals to evidence, attempts at logical argument, etc., is another matter
and evidently far more contingent. Here I personally would gesture at the
very high levels of education attained in all the countries Drezner is concerned with, and/or generations of the Flynn effect.
- Drezner is careful to explain that the changes and prospects are not all
grim. (There are real benefits to less gatekeeping, even for public
intellectuals in Drezner's sense.) He's also careful to note that in many ways
the social life of the mind has always been bad. (This is cold
comfort, but at least avoids catastrophizing.) But he leaves me convinced
that he's right about specific ways in which that social life has
recently become dysfunctional than it was, with little prospect of
improvement in the foreseeable future. §
- Disclaimer: Drezner is
a co-author
of a co-author, and a fellow relic of the
The Second Age of the
Web early '00s blogging. But I don't think we've ever met,
and I feel no obligations to read or to praise his books. (Especially not
years after they come out...)
- Cormac McCarthy, Blood Meridian, or, The Evening Redness in the West
- Re-read in memoriam. This is a strange but effective fusion of
truly ugly action and truly beautiful language. Revisiting after some decades,
I can see how it's influenced a lot of other, later books I've
read, some
for the better, some very much not.
(If it weren't for the dates, I'd think Stephen King's The
Gunslinger was in the former set.)
- Two thoughts: 1. As usual, it's a mistake to identify the opinions of
characters --- even ones who are given a lot of room to opine --- with the
opinions of the author. In particular, I see a lot of people quoting the
judge's speeches as though they were Cormac's views, but the action of the
novel makes it clear that the judge is a cunning, deceitful, possibly-inhuman
villain! He is not to be trusted!
(Reading is
hard.) 2. Something about the narration's frequent recourse to the
ancient, the primeval, to mysterious forces under the earth, etc., makes me
wonder about what Cormac thought
of Lovecraft. §
- Disclaimer: I knew Cormac
through SFI; not well, but well enough to
call him Cormac.
- Tommie Shelby, The Idea of Prison Abolition
- This is a thorough and sympathetic, but ultimately very negative,
investigation of case for abolition of prisons, from a view point that tries to
meld analytical
Marxism with what's come to be called the "black radical tradition" [1].
Much of the argument here proceeds by way of exposition and critique of the
prison-abolitionist writings of Angela Davis [2].
- Many self-proclaimed prison abolitionists seem to merely be expressing
outrage at way we treat crime through hyperbole. But some of them mean it.
(Some of them, I suspect, have
been swayed
by their own hyperbole.) In any event it's a morally serious issue, which
deserves to be examined with some care, whatever one might think of some of its
advocates. This Shelby does.
- Shelby outright dismisses the idea that society might have a legitimate
interest in meeting out
retribution for crimes [3], but accepts interests in deterrence [4], in
rehabilitation, and (I think) in incapacitation. He further explains that
consequences for anti-social behavior will only deter if they are, in
fact, unpleasant. This does not mean that those consequences need to be
horrors, but unless people would rather not experience them, they simply will
not work. Even if one wishes to emphasize gentler means that might better
serve the aims of rehabilitation and (perhaps) incapacitation, those will need
to be back-stopped by some kind of deterrence of those who are neither
rehabilitated nor incapacitated.
- Shelby tries his best to be fair to Davis's claims that the legitimate
social functions of prisons can be better served without imprisonment,
but ends up having to admit that there just isn't very much substance to those
claims. I honestly doubted whether he was really being fair to Davis here, so
at this point read her Are Prisons Obsolete?, and concluded that
Shelby was being, in fact, far too generous.
- To sum up, Shelby pretty convincingly demolishes the arguments for prison
abolition, i.e., for thinking that prisons have no place in just societies. He
is very careful to say that none of his arguments imply that current
American prisons, or our criminal justice system more generally, are
acceptable. §
- Disclaimer: I met Shelby years ago at a workshop, where I was
impressed by his presentation, and he was generous with his time in offering
suggestions on
work-then-in-progress. This
contributed to my picking up his book.
- [1]: Shelby elaborates
on his conception of his own "Afro-Analytical Marxism"
in this
2021 essay. Like most analytical Marxists, he seems more interested in
fairly orthodox historical materialism and political economy --- the sort of
topics someone shaped by the Second International, like Kautsky or Trotsky or
Luxemburg, would've recognized --- than in the
Frankfurt
School. (Davis, of course, as Marcuse's student, owes more to Frankfurt.)
Thus I think can continuing to view
Joseph
Heath as the world's leading, because only, rational-choice critical
theorist. ^
- [2]: Certain
episodes in Davis's career go (tactfully?)
unmentioned. ^
- [3]: The dismissal is
forthright, but perhaps a bit hasty. Those who are wronged by others, or their
family and friends, will tend to seek retribution from those who have wronged
them. In fact they will tend to seek disproportionate and intemperate
retribution. Such excessive retribution is both unjust itself, and apt to set
of a vicious cycle of feud and revenge. To prevent this, punishment of
wrong-doers by the state must include, and be seen to include, reasonable and
proportionate retribution. --- To be clear, I'm not saying this is
unanswerable, just that I wish Shelby hadn't dismissed retribution so swiftly.
^
- [4]: There is a
disconcerting possibility about deterrence which Shelby doesn't discuss, but
which his arguments do not, so far as I can see, foreclose. This is that
punishing people for crimes they didn't commit would have much the same
deterrent effect as punishing the guilty, so long as most
people thought that they were guilty. Someone has to suffer
in order to fulfill the legitimate public function of deterring
wrong-doing [5], but it's trickier than I'd
like to say why, ethically, it should be criminals who do the suffering. (Of
course, the task becomes easier if one believes in
retribution.) ^
- [5]: Conversely, I could easily make a case for
the authorities only convincingly pretending to punish anyone. But
such a deception would be very fragile, with bad consequences when it
unraveled; perhaps that's enough to rule it out. ^
- Bryan Burrough, Days of Rage: America's Radical Underground, the FBI, and the Forgotten Age of Revolutionary Violence
- A journalistic, but very thorough, history of violent left-wing radicals
from the late 1960s through the early 1980s. (Right-wing violence during the
same period is outside Burrough's scope, but it would make an interesting set
of comparison cases.) Many of the figures he discusses --- including Davis!
--- also show up in Shelby's book, albeit presented in rather different lights.
§
- Adolph Reed, Jr., The South: Jim Crow and Its Afterlives
- If you like Reed's essays at nonsite.org
(and I usually do), you will enjoy this, and if not, not. The marketing
material from the publisher makes it seem vastly more ambitious than it really
is, but Reed's introductory remarks make the scope clear. §
- Simon Spurrier and Matías Bergara, Coda vols. 1, 2, 3
- Comic book mind candy fantasy. Superficially, this is a cynical,
post-apocalyptic subversion of the Matter of Middle Earth. In fact, the
hard-bitten surface merely conceals a core which actually believes in
epic fantasy, both in the content and in the classical form (a trilogy ending
in a eucatastrophe). §
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur;
The Beloved Republic;
The Progressive Forces;
Philosophy;
Commit a Social Science;
The Collective Use and Evolution of Concepts;
Pleasures of Detection, Portraits of Crime;
Scientifiction and Fantastica;
Tales of Our Ancestors;
The Commonwealth of Letters
Posted at July 31, 2023 23:59 | permanent link
June 22, 2023
On Shoggothim
Attention conservation notice: Self-promotion of a pay-walled piece which combines a trendy topic with what even I admit is a long-held semi-crank notion.
Henry Farrell and I have
an essay
in The Economist, riffing off the meme that
every
large
language model is really a shoggoth. Our point is that this
is right, because an LLM is a way of taking the vast incohate chaos of
written-human-language-as-recorded-on-the-Web and simplifying and abstracting
it in potentially useful ways. They are,
as Alison
Gopnik says, cultural technologies, more analogous to library catalogs than
to individual minds. This makes LLMs recent and still-minor members of a
larger and older family of monsters which similarly simplify, abstract, and
repurpose human minds: the market system, the corporation, the state, even the
democratic state. Those are distributed information-processing
systems which don't just ingest the products of human intelligence, but
actually run on human beings --- a theme I have been sounding
for while now.
The piece is paywalled,
but Henry
has a Twitter thread that provides a good summary,
and Brad
DeLong has excerpts, along with thoughtful commentary. (I agree
with Henry's
response to said comments.) Update, 7 July: Henry links to the longer, older version we cut down for The Economist.
Some things we didn't include:
- Thanks to the editorial staff at The Economist, both for the opportunity and for their very professional work.
- Thanks to Ted Chiang (!) for helpful comments on a draft.
- Any discussion of LLMs as artifacts, in the sense of Herbert Simon's Sciences of the Artificial. (I for one learned this way of thinking of markets and hierarchies as information-processing systems from Simon...) Update, 17 August: I endorse Maxim Raginsky's treatment of this topic.
- Any discussion of Dan Sperber's account of culture as "the precipitate of cognition and communication in a human population", the role in that process of chains of alternately private-mental and public-physical representations, and LLMs as public-representation-producing artifacts
- Any discussion of Arthur Stinchcombe's work on the positive role of abstraction and formalities in institutions
- "More is different": These things emerge from the massed results of human social interaction and individual intelligence, and therefore are very different from human minds. In particular, they tend to have their own intrinsic dynamics, which are usually not things anyone intends, and often things no-one wants. (Someday I will write that essay about blackouts and alienation.) That doesn't mean they can't be controlled; it means control is hard, and usually itself impersonal.
- An adequate discussion of monster-taming and its limits, which would necessarily include extended praise of social democracy (though see DeLong's post)
- Any mention of the the primal scene of AI.
- Henry's reflections on modern neo-Lovecraftian fiction, which I hope he will publish elsewhere. Update, 7 July: see.
Update, 23 June: Small wording tweaks and additions. More important: insightful and generous commentary from Daniel "\( D^2 \)"
Davies. (It's virtually a blogosphere reunion.) Incorporated (sorry) by reference: Beniger, The Control Revolution; Yates, Control through Communication; Ashby, "Design for an Intelligence Amplifier".
(I know I learned that the correct plural of "shoggoth" is
"shoggothim" from reading Ruthanna Emrys, but I cannot now locate the passage
--- it may just be in her Lovecraft Reread series with Anne
Pillsworth.) Update: and indeed it was (tracked down by Henry).
Self-Centered;
The Collective Use and Evolution of Concepts;
Cthulhiana;
The Great Transformation
Posted at June 22, 2023 12:45 | permanent link
April 30, 2023
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, April 2023
Attention
conservation notice: I have no taste, and no qualifications to opine
on the biographies of 20th century tyrants, or the impact of the Internet on
collective creativity. Also, most of my reading this month was done at odd
hours and/or while bottle-feeding a baby, so I'm less reliable and more cranky
than usual.
- Wislawa Szymborska, Poems New and Collected, 1957--1997
- Donald Hall, Selected Poems
- I observe National Poetry Month by reading poets I really ought to have
read already. (I'd seen
Szymborska's "A
Word on Statistics", of course, IIRC from Thomas Lumley.)
- Leigh Bardugo, Hell Bent
- Mind candy fantasy / campus novel, in which Yale is literally a gateway to
Hell. It's a sequel to Ninth House, and it'll
be much more enjoyable if you read that first, but there's enough cluing-in for the new reader that it's probably not necessary. Ends in media res. §
- Andrea Fort et al., Songs for the Dead: Afterlife
- Mind candy fantasy, comic book flavor. A satisfying conclusion to
the story. §
- Robert Louis Stevenson, The Strange Case of Dr. Jekyll and Mr. Hyde
- Yes, I knew the story. No, I had never actually read it before. Yes, it's
really good. §
- Stephen Kotkin, Stalin, volumes I, Paradoxes of Power, 1878--1928 and II, Waiting for Hitler, 1929--1941
- Writing an adequately-contextual biography of Stalin means, for Kotkin,
pretty much writing a history of the world, as well as detailing the
ups and downs of Ioseb Barionis Jughashvili. I think this is right, and am
entranced at how well Kotkin tacks back and forth between different scales.
One of the themes those constant changes of scale let Kotkin explore is the
tension between large, structural forces or trends --- particularly the
imperative pressure on any state that wanted to retain independence to
industrialize
(cf.) --- and
fine-grained and contingent yet consequential facts of friendship and rivalry,
of personality, even of sheer accident. (These are very non-Marxist books,
which could only have been written by someone who had seriously wrestled with
Marxist thought.) I very eagerly await the next volume (or
volumes?). §
- Clay Shirky, Cognitive Surplus: Creativity and Generosity in a Connected Age
- Reading a 2010 book about the promise of the Internet for cooperation,
especially for intellectual collaboration, in 2023 is, well, rather melancholy.
Instead of carpooling, we have giant illegal taxi companies; instead of safe
couch-surfing, we have giant illegal hotel chains; instead of sharing
information about political violence, we have organizing political violence;
and instead of sharing information about rare medical conditions, we have
created multiple
new forms of
contagious hysteria.
- One conclusion I draw from this is that Shirky was
fundamentally right about how the Internet would unleash new forms of
collective creativity, but far, far too optimistic about the value of
that creativity.
("After all, to any
rational mind, the greater part of the history of ideas is a history of
freaks.")
- The other conclusion --- one I've been tending to for a while --- is that
as a teenager, I got caught up in a Utopian milieu, which somehow thought that
integrating the Internet, and especially the Web, into civilized life would
make things better. I spent my adult life in this environment, it was
very good to me (and I daresay to Shirky). But, thirty years later... Well, I
often find myself thinking on a passage
from Fear
and Loathing in Las Vegas, reflecting on another such hangover:
There was a fantastic universal sense that whatever we were doing was right, that we were winning...
And that, I think, was the handle --- that sense of inevitable victory over the forces of Old and Evil. Not in any mean or military sense; we didn't need that. Our energy would simply prevail. There was no point in fighting --- on our side or theirs. We had all the momentum; we were riding the crest of a high and beautiful wave...
So now, less than five years later, you can go up on a steep hill in Las Vegas and look West, and with the right kind of eyes you can almost see the high-water mark --- that place where the wave finally broke and rolled back.
- Shirky was offering a view from the crest of the wave. This one didn't
exactly break and roll back; it just left the same old rubbish as before in
its wake, only sodden and salt-rimed. This is, perhaps, the best a utopia
can hope to achieve. §
- Disclaimer: I'd forgotten, until I was
almost ready to post this, that back in
the Second Age of the
Web 2003--2004 Shirky and I were both parties to
a discussion
involving the
exact shape of the degree
distribution for weblogs. That dispute is irrelevant to the subject of
this book, and has no bearing on my views of it. (For the record: he was wrong
about the degree distribution.)
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur;
Writing for Antiquity;
The Progressive Forces;
Linkage;
The Collective Use and Evolution of Concepts;
Actually, "Dr. Internet" Is the Name of the Monsters' Creator;
Scientifiction and Fantastica;
The Commonwealth of Letters
Posted at April 30, 2023 23:59 | permanent link
|