Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, July 2008
- Nicolò
Cesa-Bianchi and Gábor
Lugosi, Prediction, Learning, and Games
- A wonderful synthesis of the literature on competitive, individual-sequence
forecasting with expert advice. That is, the problems considered are all
variants on a situation where you need to make a prediction about the future
(or more generally take an action whose consequences will only be revealed in
the future), have access to a range of "experts" or forecasting algorithms, and
want to ensure that, no matter what actually happens, your performance will be
close to that of the best expert. This is thus a study of sequential
decision-making under uncertainty without probability. Often, but not
always, the solution lies in taking weighted averages of the experts, giving
more weight to those which have done well in the past. This works not because
past performance provides any kind of inductive evidence of future success, but
merely because it keeps your predictions from drifting too far from what is, in
fact, working. (Perversely, many of the proofs rely on probabilistic
arguments, but they don't make probabilistic assumptions.) Of course, it may
be that even the best expert is very bad, but the possibility of
improving on the experts is not really considered, though it's certainly
possible (at least with convex loss functions).
- Anyone at all interested in machine learning, forecasting, information,
game theory, or decision-making under uncertainty needs to read this.
It may also be useful to epistemologists (cf.).
- Max Brooks, World War Z: An Oral History of the Zombie War
- An oral history (a la Studs Terkel) of the early 21st-century global
struggle against the zombie apocalypse (a la George Romero). This is a happy
choice of form, because it lets him tell the story of a global disaster from
many viewpoints, without taking the space which would be required in a
conventional cast-of-thousands novel. Also, he gets to tell lots of variously
creepy, horrifying, thrilling, and/or moving stories this way.
- Query: does this qualify as a "modern epic", sensu Moretti?
- Marc Van De Mieroop, The Ancient Mesopotamian City
- As every school-child knows,
"history
begins at Sumer", with the first cities and the first writing. This book
is the only accessible synoptic view of the cities of ancient Mesopotamia as
such.
- After opening by quoting some jaw-droppingly ignorant (and recent) remarks
by classicists on how there were no real cities before the Greeks, Van
De Mieroop describes the geographic scene, and lays out some of the limitations
on our evidence — peculiarities in what scribes thought worth recording,
and other peculiarities in what archaeologists have thought worth excavating.
Next he considers theories of the origins of cities in Mesopotamia, a
peculiarly difficult problem since there were no other cities to learn from or
be influenced by. He favors the idea that they originated around the temples,
which acted as institutions for redistributing the products of multiple
ecological regions, but he is fair to other ideas. (He is even fair to Jane
Jacobs's wacky idea that cities preceded, and caused, agriculture, which is to
say he does some simple calculations to show it makes no sense whatsoever.) He
then goes on to consider social organization, leading institutions like the
palace and the temple, the hints of self-government among city-dwellers and
their growth over time, the relations between cities and their agricultural
hinterlands, how food moved into the cities, long-distance trade, credit and
finance, and cities as centers of religion and learning, including divination
and astronomy. (He says scribes were taught "calculus", presumably meaning
"calculation".) He quotes frequently from Mesopotamian documents, without any
philological apparatus, and despite a ritual rejection of strict "positivism",
he is very cautious in advancing hypotheses, and very good about marking
conjectures as such, and emphasizing that we simply have little or no evidence
about many matters.
- Mesopotamian history is usually considered to last from the first writing
around -3100 to the Macedonian conquests around -300. As Van De Mieroop says,
this period of 2800 years is longer than the interval separating us from Homer.
It is an astonishing act of hubris, or at least of abstraction, to try to
summarize the features of all cities over such a period, even in a
restricted region — one can only presume that there must have been
extensive variation. Nonetheless, Van De Mieroop does a really remarkable
job.
- Lucy
Snyder, Installing Linux on a Dead Badger
- You remember "Installing Linux on a Dead Badger", don't you?
Well, imagine a full hundred page book of such stories. C'mon, you know you
want it.
- Jack
Campbell, Valiant
- Continuing science-fictional anabasis;
see here for previous
installments.
- Charles
E. Lindblom and David
K. Cohen Usable Knowledge: Social Science and Social Problem
Solving
- This is a short (100 pp.) book from 1979, largely given over to sketches of
arguments and directions for further inquiry (mostly not undertaken in the
ensuing years) about why the social sciences, and "professional social inquiry"
more generally, have not been very directly useful for social problem solving.
They suggest that this rests on a number of basic widespread mistakes about how
social problems are solved. In particular, they allege, social scientists
vastly under-rate the importance and competence of ordinary-life social
knowledge, and, yet more consequentially, fail to see that social problems can
be solved either by analyzing them in some discursive/analytic
form, or by setting up patterns of social interaction where the
participants' acts collectively solve the problem, though none of them need to
grasp the solution or even realize that is what they are doing. Markets are of
course one example of such "interactive problem solving", but they also, and
quite correctly, emphasize others: democratic politics, bargaining processes,
and the "republic of science". They emphasize that interactive problem-solving
should not be seen as a poor substitute for formal problem solving, to be
displaced in due time by scientifically-informed social engineering, but rather
as inevitable, and indeed often superior.
- The alternative, of analytically finding solutions to social problems, is
basically impossible, because the problems are too complex, and even systematic
investigation into them is not just prohibitively expensive, but so slow that
the world has moved on before research findings can become very accurate or
precise. (Obviously these obstacles can all be bigger or smaller in various
cases, and I don't think they'd quibble if someone wanted to assert that very
small, stable social problems could be successfully analyzed if enough
resources were thrown at them.) Worse, the very definitions of "social
problems" are themselves contested, and properly so. The authors' view is
that while the natural sciences can (often) legitimately claim independent
authority, for social scientists to aim at such authority is to set themselves
a target they cannot possibly hit. Since they do aim at that target, however,
social scientists and other "practitioners of professional social inquiry"
systematically waste their efforts.
- Given all this, fruitful roles for social analysts become things like
advising individual participants in the interactions, or looking at the
over-all performance of an interactive mechanism and searching for ways in
which it might be improved. (They suggest that economists are better about
this than other social scientists. Given the recent vogue among economists for
replacing all kinds of institutions with arbitrary intellectual constructions,
planned by analogy with the idealized markets of their Micro 1 textbooks, I
suspect the authors might wish to revise and extend these remarks.) A further,
if more diffusive, constructive role would be in hoping to shape the general
framework within which participants in interactive problem-solving think about
things; and of course the kind of detailed reportage which statistical bureaus
engage in.
- The name "Hayek" does not appear anywhere in this book.
- Douglas W. Tallamy, Bringing Nature Home: How Native Plants Sustain Wildlife in Our Gardens
- This is a rather straight-forward argument for North American suburbanites
(and urbanites, too) to plant more native plants, roughly as follows. (1) We
like having wildlife such as birds and (some) mammals around. (2) These
animals sit high in the food-web; below them are many insects, especially
insect larvae. (3) Most insects are specialized to eat only a small range of
plants with which they have co-evolved, in no small part because of the
chemical defenses evolved by plants. (4) Thus, native plants support a much
larger and much more diverse population of insects than do introduced ones.
(5) The process of evolutionary adaptation is very slow, and even plants
introduced almost 500 years ago are still substantially less good as insect
hosts than natives. (6) Suburbia occupies such a huge part of the American
landscape that if native plants are to thrive anywhere, it has to be there.
Therefore, (7) suburbanites should shift what they plant towards natives.
- Obviously, the key empirical parts of this argument are (4) and (5); here
the evidence that Tallamy presents is good, but — he is admirably
up-front about this — not conclusive, and he is happy to admit that there
are some species of introduced plants which are so closely related to natives
that bugs like them just fine. Unlike many books on native plants, this is
empirical, consequentialist, modest, and un-mystical.
- David
Pollard, Empirical Processes: Theory and Applications (full
text free
online)
- The simplest sort of empirical process arises when trying to estimate a
probability distribution from sample data. The difference between the
empirical
distribution function \( F_n(x) \) and the true distribution function \(
F(x) \) converges to zero everywhere (by the law of large numbers), and —
this is non-trivial — the maximum difference between the
empirical and true distribution functions converges to zero, too (by
the Glivenko-Cantelli
theorem, a uniform law of large numbers). The "empirical process" \(
E_n(x) \) is the re-scaled difference, \( \sqrt{n} \left[ F_n(x) - F(x) \right]
\), and it converges to a Gaussian stochastic process that only
depends on the true distribution (by
the functional
central limit theorem). Empirical process theory is concerned with
generalizing this sort of material to other stochastic processes determined by
random samples, and indexed by infinite classes (like the real line, or the
class of all Borel sets on the line, or some space parameterizing a regression
model). The typical objects of concern are proving uniform limit theorems, and
with establishing distributional limits. (For instance, one might one want to
prove that the errors of all possible regression models in some class
will come close to their expected errors, so that maximum-likelihood or
least-squares estimation is consistent. [For more on that line of thought,
see Sara van de Geer's book
on Empirical
Processes in M-Estimation.]) This endeavor is closely linked to
Vapnik-Chervonenkis-style learning
theory, and in fact one can see VC theory as an application of empirical
process theory. (I'd guess Vapnik himself would disagree with that,
however.)
- This short book by Pollard is an introduction to empirical process theory
by a statistician for statisticians. As such it succeeds admirably; as always,
Pollard does a really good job of explaining what the technical apparatus is
doing and why it takes the form it does. People coming to it from other
backgrounds (I am particularly thinking of computer scientists) will probably
find it harder going, not least because the implied reader has an extremely
sure grasp on measure theory. (Such as one might acquire from, oh,
Pollard's User's Guide
to Measure-Theoretic Probability.) If you can handle
Pollard's 1989
survey paper, then you will probably enjoy this book; and if not, not.
The applications he describes are all interesting and challenging, though
I was a bit disappointd that none of them involve dependent data.
- Clubbing
- Fall of Cthulhu: The Fugue
- Scalped: Indian Country
- Proof: Goatsucker
- Various flavors of comic-book mind-candy. Sequels to Scalped:
2--4, 5
- Jenny Davidson, The Explosionist
- It is impossible to describe this better than the author, so I'll
steal her words:
the story of a 15-year-old girl growing up in an alternate version of 1930s Edinburgh, one where the legacy of Napoleon's victory a century earlier at Waterloo is a standoff between a totalitarian Federation of European States and a group of independent northern countries called the New Hanseatic League. This world is preoccupied with technology (everything from electric cookers to high explosives) but also with spiritualism, a movement our world largely abandoned in the early twentieth century; Sigmund Freud is a radio talk-show crank, cars run on hydrogen and the most prominent scientists experiment with new ways of contacting the dead.
- My biggest complaint with this book is that it ends in the middle of the story, and nothing warns the reader about this. Grrrr.
- Charles Tilly, Democracy
- An attempt to explain the mechanisms by which states come to engage in
"broad, equal, protected, mutually-binding consultation" with their citizens,
singling out three especially important processes: (1) integrating "trust
networks" into public politics, (2) screening off public politics from
categorical forms of inequality, and (3) suppressing non-state centers of
coercive power. As usual with Tilly, he draws on a huge range of historical
sources, in an impressive display of erudition and clear thinking. Also as
usual with Tilly, one does not get a comprehensive theory, but perhaps this is
the sort of material where such a theory isn't really possible, and the best
one can hope for is a catalog of recurring mechanisms.
- Charles Tilly, Big Structures, Large Processes, Huge Comparisons
- A brisk debunking of pernicious ideas about how societies work and change
that we have inherited from the 19th century, together with a smart and
enthusiastic brief for comparative, historical social science. (The
description at Powell's is definitely for another book!)
- Thanks to Doug White for
lending me his copy.
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur;
Enigmas of Chance;
Biology;
Scientifiction and Fantastica;
Pleasures of Detection;
The Dismal Science;
Cthulhiana;
Writing for Antiquity
Posted at July 31, 2008 23:59 | permanent link