Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur, April 2015
Attention
conservation notice: I have no taste.
- Christian Caryl, Strange Rebels: 1979 and the Birth of the 21st Century
- A very nicely written popular history of five movements that either began
or reached a peak in 1979: the Iranian Revolution, the Soviet-Afghan War, Deng
Xiaoping's economic reforms in China, Margaret Thatacher's government in
Britain, and John Paul II's first visit as Pope to Poland, viewed as part of a
moral campaign against the Soviet Union. Caryl, quite rightly, views these all
as anticipations of trends that have come to shape our world, and look like to
keep shaping the 21st century --- the economic rise of China, the collapse of
Soviet Communism, neoliberalism, Islamism. (I don't believe he ever uses the
word "neoliberal" or its derivatives.) Beyond the coincidence of dates, he
also links them through their opposition to what, for most of the 20th century,
could have been seen as its dominant trends of secularization and
socialism, though he's very careful to note how, e.g., post-revolutionary Iran
retained and even amplified many modernization initiatives of the Shah's
regime, or how Thatcher left alone much of the British welfare state. (He has
a nice passage, which irritatingly I cannot find again, about how it's much
easier to be a rugged individualist when you know you can go to a hospital for
free if you're sick, and will have a guaranteed pension when you're too old to
work.) He is also, mercifully, restrained in claiming causal connections
between these events — the biggest is how much the USSR's military
commitments in Afghanistan limited its ability to use force in eastern Europe
— or abstract, thematic parallels. I think he's too inclined to give
credit to Thatcher's economic policies, but otherwise I have few complaints or
quibbles. Recommended.
- Sydney Padua, The Thrilling Adventures of
Lovelace and Babbage: The (Mostly) True Story of the First Computer
- If you enjoy this weblog, it is very likely that you are part of
the target audience for an irregular comic,
in which Lovelace and Babbage were hived off into a pocket universe in which
they actually built the Analytic Engine, and used it to fight crime. This is
precisely that comic, with footnotes and a bonus material about how the Engine
would have looked and worked. I recommend it very highly.
- Michael Ellman, Socialist Planning
- A sort of soberer older cousin to Red
Plenty; at least in the first edition of 1979, which is what I read.
(I am curious to see what
revisions Ellman made later, since 1979 was of course when things began to
change radically...)
- The book primarily attends to the USSR and its satellites in eastern
Europe; the secondary focus is on China. (There are occasional discussions of
Yugoslavia and Cuba, and mentions of the Communist governments of southeast
Asia, but nothing about how they actually ran things; and I don't believe North
Korea is ever named at all.) There was a lot of interesting and valuable
detail about how the Soviets actually drew up plans and tried to implement
them. About China Ellman had to be sketchier, because there was simply so
little available information, and because the process was itself more chaotic.
(While Ellman was evidently more skeptical about Maoism and the Cultural
Revolution than many westerners were in the 1970s, this is one places where I
hope he'd like to revise and extend his remarks.) Indeed, from reading Ellman,
I find myself doubting that pre-Deng China really had economic plans,
as opposed to mere orders...
- Ellman's attempts to draw up some sort of assessment of the accomplishments
and defects of state socialism tries to do this from both a liberal and a
Marxist perspective. I think he wasn't harsh enough on the ways
capitalist countries fail liberalism, or on the ways state socialist
countries failed socialism. Whether what's come since in the former
second world is an improvement from either point of view is a more
complex question, which this book is necessarily silent on.
- Gene Wolfe, Sword of the Lictor
- In which Severian commits another crime of mercy, wanders in the wilderness
(much of it consisting
of relics of
former civilizations), and is offered all the kingdoms of the world if he
will but fall down and worship a resurrected two-headed tyrant. Also, a story
is told which is somewhere between the myth of Romulus and Remus, and The
Jungle Book.
- I wish I understood how exactly Wolfe manages to convey the sense that he
understands all the mysteries he is hinting at, without actually explaining
much of anything. (Previously: 1,
2;
subsequently: 4)
- Milovan
Djilas, The New Class: An Analysis of the Communist
System
- Djilas was probably the highest-ranking member of any ruling Communist
party to become an anti-Communist. This was his 1957 attempt at an explanation
of what Communist governments, like the one he helped found in Yugoslavia, were
actually up to. This analysis was plainly very strongly influenced by
Marxism, because it's all about class struggle and the over-riding historical
imperative of enhancing production. Dividing through for some of that,
Djilas's big idea is that Communism amounted to collective ownership, not by
the whole people, but by a "new class" of economic managers and party
functionaries. This new class pursued rapid industrialization partly so they
would have more to exploit, but even more so as to not be utterly overwhelmed
by the advanced capitalist countries. Having a superior position to other
classes within the countries they ruled, they naturally used it in
self-interested ways; thus class conflict, far from being eliminated, persists.
Djilas explains Communist dictatorship, suppression of freedom of thought and
other civil liberties, etc., as the new class's means of maintaining its firm
position of collective ownership against possible threats, not so much from
reactionaries as from other classes. (Cf. the much
later joke about Brezhnev's
mother.) I have to confess that I cannot follow his explanation of why the
new class's relations of production are incompatible with
democracy within the Party, or even with "formal" democracy for the country as
a whole. (After all, capitalist and even slave-owning societies have been
compatible with republicanism and democracy for privileged classes.) While
recognizing the diminution of the intensity of repression after Stalin, Djilas
emphasized that this involved no change in principle or actual entrenchment of
rights the state and party were bound to respect.
- As I said, this strikes me as not just more-or-less Marxist but an
amplification of the Trotskyist view of what went wrong in the USSR --- though
without Trotsky's need to justify the 1917 Revolution and his own actions in
helping build the Soviet state. That is, Djilas doesn't regard the new class
as some sort of bureaucratic degeneration of a workers' state, still less a
reactionary restoration of capitalism, but rather as the logical end-point of
the Communist trajectory.
- Wisely, Djilas offered no concrete forecasts as to what would happen to the
Communist governments. I don't feel competent to say whether subsequent events
were compatible with his theory.
- There was a curious after-life to Djilas's theory of the "new class", since
it was picked up by American neo-conservatives
and used
as a club in the culture wars. Their theory was (I am not making this up)
that a tendency to social and cultural liberalism on the part of teachers,
journalists and entertainers is just like the apparatchiks' complete
control of the economic resources and repressive force of totalitarian states.
There is thus a (thin, twisty, strained) line of intellectual descent from
Djilas to clowns like Glenn Beck; it would be grimly amusing to read a full
history of this some day.
- Gareth
Hinds, MacBeth
- A graphic-novel adaptation, aimed at younger readers. The selections from
the text, and minor modernizations to vocabulary, are all well-chosen. More
important, the drawing is excellent, and actually really amplifies the text; I
doubt I will ever see Lady MacBeth, the witches, or Banquo other than this way.
(Hinds's MacBeth will however compete in my memory
with Toshiro Mifune.)
- Disclaimer: Hinds is married to a friend of my brother's. This is
how I came to look at his book, but has no (conscious) bearing on my review.
- Ian Tregillis, The Mechanical
- Mind candy: a sort of alternate-historical fantasy, in which Huygens,
evidently by stealing ideas from Newton, invented alchemical-mechanical golems
(called "clakkers"), leading to the Dutch taking over all of the world except
for New France, home of the Papacy and French monarchy in exile. Of course,
clakkers turn out to be conscious, to experience excruciating pain when they
receive orders, and to have some mysterious means of liberation... (There is
a lot about Spinoza, which will probably become clearer in the
inevitable sequels.) It's catnip for those who have spent far too much time
reading about 17th-century science and philosophy, especially in the United
Provinces, while simultaneously liking fantasy.
- Tregillis's self-presentation.
- Marie Brennan, Voyage of the Basilisk
- Mind candy. I enjoyed it, but I suspect it's only for those who have
read previous installments
in Lady Trent's adventures. — Sequel.
- David Brion Davis, Inhuman Bondage: The Rise and Fall of Slavery in the New World
- Popular history by a respected historian. (He says at the beginning that
it began as notes for a short course for high school teachers, which strikes me
as an excellent thing.) While slavery in the United States occupies most of
the book, Davis is very good at setting that in the context of slavery
throughout the Americas (as the subtitle indicates), and indeed the broader
historical context of slavery in Europe, southwest Asia and Africa. What
becomes depressingly clear from reading this (if it wasn't already) is just how
utterly central slavery was to the formation of the modern world economy and to
the European colonization of the Americas, and just how monstrous an
institution it was. I can't decide if that makes the first word of the title
well-chosen, or if it shouldn't rather force us to define down our notion of
what acting like a human being means. (One must imagine Simon Legree saying
"Am I not a man and a brother?") That abolitionism became a serious movement
anywhere, let alone one which was able to succeed in some countries through the
force of mere persuasion, is almost as astonishingly hopeful as the history of
slavery is depressing. Davis's narrative of the slave power within the US,
culminating in enormously destructive treason in defense of slavery (*), is
exemplary, as is the treatment of Lincoln and the failure of reconstruction.
- *: I cannot now recall where I learned this apt
phrase; Davis does not, I believe, use it.
- Randal Douc, Eric Moulines and David S. Stoffer, Nonlinear Time Series: Theory, Methods, and Applications with R Examples [R code, errata, data]
- This is a thorough, but introductory, treatment of the statistical
theory of parametric nonlinear time series models, illustrated with
many concrete mathematical and data-analytic examples. The emphasis is however
on the theory, I think quite rightly, because the theory is crucial for
understanding what methods work and why they do so.
- The book consists of three parts, only loosely linked. Part I is on basic
time series models and methods: it reduces all of linear-Gaussian model theory
to two chapters, including ARMA, time- and frequency- domain methods, and the
linear Gaussian state-space model. Chapters 3 and 4 tour various nonlinear
models, mostly parametric ones, and illustrate some of the need for
non-linearities.
- Part II (chapters 5--8) is a short course on
the ergodic theory of
Markov processes. Like everyone else since the early 1990s, their
treatment of this subject is heavily influenced
by Meyn and Tweedie's Markov Chains
and Stochastic Stability. Douc et al. particularly emphasize
uniform and V-geometric ergodicity, that is, conditions under which a Markov
process's state distribution converges exponentially fast to an invariant or
equilibrium distribution. (The ugly phrase "V-geometric" combines the notion
of an exponential or geometric convergence rate with a particular way of
measuring distance between distributions, generalizing total variation or $L_1$
distance.) Given rapid convergence of distributions, especially with
calculable rates, one can get limit theorems about time averages, both
almost-sure ("Birkhoff") limit theorems which, like the law of large numbers,
say that time averages converge on expectation values, and central limit
theorems giving the Gaussian fluctuations around the limits. These in turn
provide the foundations for maximum likelihood estimation of Markov models, and
what Douc et al.,
following Cox (sec. 3.2),
call "observation-driven" models, a.k.a.
chains with complete connections or stochastic
automata. Many of the specific models from Part I reappear in this
part as examples, but I believe one could read Part II without ever
looking at Part I.
- Part III is about state-space or hidden Markov models, where there is a
latent or hidden state that evolves according to a Markov process, and we
observe a noisy, generally nonlinear, function of the state. The special case
where the state evolves linearly, the observation is linear in the state, and
all noise terms are Gaussian allows for an exact treatment, given in chapter 2.
The other special case where the state and the observation are both discrete
also allows for exact treatment,
the EM
algorithm (as originally invented
by Baum and Welch).
The key problems for state-space models is that of estimating the current state
given all observations up to the present, called "filtering", and estimating
the sequence of states over some time interval given observations over a
(possibly longer) interval, called "smoothing". If the model parameters are
known, then the solution to both problems is given formally by Bayes's rule
(cf.), but of
course it cannot actually be calculated, so one must approximate.
- Chapters 10 and 11 explain the "particle" approach to filtering and
smoothing. The particle filter is easier to explain than the particle
smoother, so I'll stick with the former. Start by randomly drawing $N$
"particles" in the hidden state space according to the initial state
distribution, call these $X_0^1, X_0^2, \ldots X_0^N$. (The subscript
indicates time, the super-script indexes particles.) Then have each particle
evolve its state independently, according to the Markov process for the states,
so $p(\tilde{X}_1^i|X_0^i) = q(X_0^i,\tilde{X}_1^i)$ for the fixed Markov
kernel $q$ describing the state evolution. (Remember, we're assuming the
parameters are known for the moment.) Now take the first observation $Y_1$.
It will have some conditional probability (or probability density) given each
particle's state, $p(Y_1| \tilde{X}_1^i) = r(\tilde{X}_1^i, Y_1)$. Resample
the particles with probabilities proportional to the $r(\tilde{X}_1^i, Y_1)$,
so that we get $N$ particles $X_1^1, X_1^2, \ldots X_1^N$. It is not hard to
convince oneself that (as $N\rightarrow\infty$) the distribution of $X_1$
particles converges on the actual distribution $p(X_1|Y_1)$. Now evolve the
$X_1$ particles to get $\tilde{X}_2$ and repeat the cycle with the next
observation, $Y_2$. Moreover, by throwing enough particles at the problem, we
get a consistent approximation to $p(X_t|Y_1, \ldots Y_t)$, and this
approximation can even be kept up over time.
- Chapter 12 extends particle filtering and smoothing to likelihood-based
inference, i.e., to approximating, $p(Y_1, \ldots Y_n; \theta)$, where the
parameter $\theta$ now influences both the state evolution (above, $q$) and the
observation mechanism (above, $r$). Given a decent approximation to the
likelihood, one can (with some care) maximize it, or one can dilute its
evidence about $\theta$ with a prior and do Bayesian inference. Chapter 13
provides a very nice information-theoretic treatment of the consistency and
asymptotic efficiency of maximum likelihood, without presuming that the model
is well-specified. The consistency of Bayesian inference is not touched on,
which may be just as well because it's
a much harder problem.
- The mathematical exercises are good; I confess I didn't try the
computational ones. I would be very happy to use this book for a graduate
course in time series theory, emphasizing Parts II and III, and probably
combined with Fan and Yao for
non-parametric models,
and/or Gourieroux
and Monfort for simulation-based inference of scientific models.
- Disclaimer: I know Prof. Stoffer slightly, which is, I presume,
why the publisher sent me an unsolicited review-copy of this book last
year.
Books to Read While the Algae Grow in Your Fur;
Scientifiction and Fantastica;
Enigmas of Chance;
The Dismal Science;
Writing for Antiquity;
The Continuing Crises;
The Great Transformation;
The Commonwealth of Letters;
Automata and Calculating Machines;
Afghanistan and Central Asia;
The Beloved Republic
Posted at April 30, 2015 23:59 | permanent link